
Economics & Growth | Fiscal Policy
Economics & Growth | Fiscal Policy
Income and wealth inequality have become political flashpoints in recent years. Yet the exact origin of wealth inequality remains murky. Do people get rich based largely on income earned in the labour market? Do large capital gains on real and financial assets matter more? And to whom? Or is wealth inherited, as French economist Thomas Piketty argues?
A new NBER working paper uses a unique Norwegian dataset that studies individuals’ wealth over 20 years. They look at segments of the population, including the super-rich. They find:
Current wealth proxies potential wealth well, particularly for those at the top. That is, the wealthier an individual is today, the more likely they are to be wealthy in the future.
Labour income is the most important determinant of wealth, except among the top 1%. Meanwhile, inheritances and gifts do not drive wealth outcomes, even among the top 1%.
Equalising wages and increasing government transfers to poorer cohorts compresses the wealth distribution, while higher returns on real estate and risky financial assets widen it.
Parental wealth significantly influences child wealth. Children of the top 1% receive greater inheritances and invest these resources to receive a disproportional amount of their wealth from capital income.
This article is only available to Macro Hive subscribers. Sign-up to receive world-class macro analysis with a daily curated newsletter, podcast, original content from award-winning researchers, cross market strategy, equity insights, trade ideas, crypto flow frameworks, academic paper summaries, explanation and analysis of market-moving events, community investor chat room, and more.
Income and wealth inequality have become political flashpoints in recent years. Yet the exact origin of wealth inequality remains murky. Do people get rich based largely on income earned in the labour market? Do large capital gains on real and financial assets matter more? And to whom? Or is wealth inherited, as French economist Thomas Piketty argues?
A new NBER working paper uses a unique Norwegian dataset that studies individuals’ wealth over 20 years. They look at segments of the population, including the super-rich. They find:
The authors create a sample of individuals aged between 26 and 46 in 1994 and record their net wealth at that time. They then also record all the income received from various sources every year from 1995 to 2013. The authors use administrative data on wealth collected from a tax-based register, unique to only a handful of countries. By design, this is more informative than survey-based data used across EU countries. They measure wealth in four ways:
Spending doesn’t impact wealth unless you have children
First, the authors check the correlation between net wealth and potential wealth in 2013. Given the difference between the two relates purely to consumption habits, a high correlation suggests that differences in spending and consumption patterns are not a large component of differences in wealth across individuals.
The correlation is high (0.78) and higher for the wealthy in particular. This suggests the wealthy tend to remain wealthy regardless of their spending habits. They also find that net wealth and potential wealth diverge most when households have children, when the majority of their income is labour income, and when they inherit less.
Capital matters for the 1%
Next, the paper examines wealth’s origins. Potential wealth is disproportionately composed of labour income, especially for the bottom 80% of the wealth distribution, with capital gains on real assets (e.g. houses) also playing a big part. For the top 1%, capital gains are the main source of wealth (Chart 2). On the other hand, inheritance and gifts represent only a very small share regardless of wealth (note these are shares – the value of gifts and inheritance varies substantially).
The origins of wealth also depend on age. The importance of labour income declines as individuals age, while capital income and, especially, transfer income (which includes pension income) play a larger role. Inheritance and gifts initially play no role, then they increase in significance during middle age before petering out again.
The paper’s method lends itself to the use of counterfactuals. For example, what if the wealthy received a 100% tax on inheritance? In total, the authors create five counterfactual scenarios:
Yes! The authors show that individuals with rich parents get their wealth disproportionately from capital income and returns on financial wealth. This source of wealth is very different from children with poorer parents, who continue to rely significantly on labour income (Chart 4).
Interestingly, the authors show inheritance is not the main driver of a wealthy child’s potential wealth. But they suggest it could still play a role. For example, in absolute terms, wealthy children will receive larger sums of inheritance (say £100,000 vs £10,000). They then invest these resources into financial investments so that they receive a disproportionate amount of capital income in the future. In essence, inheritance crowds-in other forms of income.
This paper makes an important distinction in wealth inequality. The wealth inequality of the top 1% is mainly due to capital, while the wealth inequality in the rest of the population is mainly due to labour income differences. Moreover, inheritance appears not to drive inequality. This has significant policy implications. Policies that tax inheritance are largely political and have little impact on wealth disparities. Government transfers should be conditional on wealth, otherwise they increase inequality. Children with wealthy parents accumulate income through different sources; these sources mean they are likely to remain wealthy in the future.
Spring sale - Prime Membership only £3 for 3 months! Get trade ideas and macro insights now
Your subscription has been successfully canceled.
Discount Applied - Your subscription has now updated with Coupon and from next payment Discount will be applied.