
COVID | Monetary Policy & Inflation
COVID | Monetary Policy & Inflation
As the fight against COVID-19 continues, we ask: what lessons from war mobilisation can be employed to fight pandemics? Looking at this working paper from the Global Institute for Sustainable Prosperity, we consider the justification of large-scale fiscal stimulus to maintain the productive capacity of the economy. What the paper also demonstrates is that the longer the economy stays in lockdown, the higher the likelihood of stagflation returning.
What is Mobilisation Economics?
Normally, a market economy is geared towards maximising individual liberty. A mobilised economy works towards maximising society’s welfare by devoting all of its human capital, institutional capacity and its resources to a shared goal. For example, winning a war; or, in the current situation, flattening the curve.
This article is only available to Macro Hive subscribers. Sign-up to receive world-class macro analysis with a daily curated newsletter, podcast, original content from award-winning researchers, cross market strategy, equity insights, trade ideas, crypto flow frameworks, academic paper summaries, explanation and analysis of market-moving events, community investor chat room, and more.
As the fight against COVID-19 continues, we ask: what lessons from war mobilisation can be employed to fight pandemics? Looking at this working paper from the Global Institute for Sustainable Prosperity, we consider the justification of large-scale fiscal stimulus to maintain the productive capacity of the economy. What the paper also demonstrates is that the longer the economy stays in lockdown, the higher the likelihood of stagflation returning.
Normally, a market economy is geared towards maximising individual liberty. A mobilised economy works towards maximising society’s welfare by devoting all of its human capital, institutional capacity and its resources to a shared goal. For example, winning a war; or, in the current situation, flattening the curve.
Prolonged quarantines could force us into a tight mobilisation scenario. But we could exit it by closing the inflationary gap, either through demand management or by releasing workers from their homes to increase output. However, broad-scale mobilisation of idle resources towards fighting the virus does not appear forthcoming (as there is also a risk of speeding the spread of the virus). So, we might not approach an inflationary gap in the first place.
The quarantine of workers will reduce real GDP significantly. These represent goods that nobody can consume because they were never produced — that’s a real loss. However, somebody must bear the real loss. This can happen through a reduction in aggregate demand, as people who reduce their expenditures are in effect self-selecting to take the real loss. But if too few people self-select — that is, if the drop in demand ends up being smaller than the decline in production — then this will set up an inflationary dynamic as buyers compete for a limited amount of resources, potentially driving up prices.
It’s worth noting that economists seem optimistic that the demand gap will be higher than the supply shortages. So a general shortage-induced inflation is not a worry in the short run. Similarly, that Washington is spending trillions on a scale last seen in WWII is another signal that the demand gap is more significant than the supply shortage.
While inflation may not appear on an aggregate scale, specific products and sectors may require regulating, such as critical medical goods, which could experience shortages and consequently price increases. The authors of the working paper advocate some form of price control or controls on inventory (i.e. limiting the quantity of a particular product or material a firm may stockpile) and distribution orders (i.e. requiring a supplier to maintain distributions to specific customers or geography). The federal government’s current action where individual US states could procure their own supplies, effectively pitting them against each other in the market for critical goods, could become inflationary and create shortages for some states.
Following war, demand spikes before supply resumes (it takes time before war-torn capacity is rebuilt) leading to both price rises and unemployment — a situation known as stagflation. Demobilisation following COVID-19 should ensure this does not occur. The main goal is to preserve productive capacity in stasis until it’s functional again, which requires steps to ensure supply side does not experience structural damage when labour quarantined. The private economy needs to absorb workers re-entering once the quarantines end. That will depend critically on whether during quarantine business is paused or whether, during shut down, they have fired the workforce, sold capital and filed for bankruptcy. If it is the former, then the return to a healthy economy will be smoother. If not, then we may face wartime-like stagflation.
The paper highlights how war can be inflationary, but that such an eventuality may not always be so for pandemics. It also sheds light on how the main goals of a coronavirus stabilisation policy will not be to redirect productive capacity (unlike war). Instead, it will be to preserve productive capacity. The paper implicitly justifies large-scale fiscal stimulus to ensure that the productive capacity of the economy is not damaged. And it also demonstrates that the longer the lockdown continues, the higher the likelihood of stagflation returning.
Spring sale - Prime Membership only £3 for 3 months! Get trade ideas and macro insights now
Your subscription has been successfully canceled.
Discount Applied - Your subscription has now updated with Coupon and from next payment Discount will be applied.