
Monetary Policy & Inflation | US
Monetary Policy & Inflation | US
This article is only available to Macro Hive subscribers. Sign-up to receive world-class macro analysis with a daily curated newsletter, podcast, original content from award-winning researchers, cross market strategy, equity insights, trade ideas, crypto flow frameworks, academic paper summaries, explanation and analysis of market-moving events, community investor chat room, and more.
The Trump administration’s first few weeks have been challenging for investors. Equity markets have lost all their post-election gains amid multiple and inconsistent policy announcements. Here, I attempt to provide a framework to interpret the administration’s many policy initiatives.
I think Trump’s overarching objective is to solidify and extend the move of blue-collar Americans to the Republican party by raising their real income (Chart 1). If successful, such a move could have deep macro and market consequences. However, this entails substantial implementation risks.
Since the 1970s, low wages have barely increased in real terms while average real wages have risen 70% (Chart 2). But even average wages have increased by much less than productivity and employees’ share of national income has been on a multi-decades’ downtrend (Chart 3).
Secretary Scott Bessent wants to address this issue when stating, ‘It is Main Street time, Wall Street will do well enough but perhaps not as well as in the past’ and that the administration is focused on small businesses and consumers rather than on financial markets performance.
But the administration’s strategy to raise lower income Americans is a break with the past: it aims to improve their labour market outcomes rather than tax and redistribute income (Chart 4).
The administration’s strategy to raise real incomes is five pronged.
Of these, I argue the most powerful intervention is immigration. As Professor George Borjas explains, ’because a disproportionate percentage of immigrants have few skills, it is low-skilled American workers, including many blacks and Hispanics, who have suffered most from this wage dip. The monetary loss is sizable. The typical high school dropout earns about $25,000 annually. According to census data, immigrants admitted in the past two decades lacking a high school diploma have increased the size of the low-skilled workforce by roughly 25 percent. As a result, the earnings of this particularly vulnerable group dropped by between $800 and $1,500 each year.’
And this was in 2016, before the recent immigration surge.
In think trend growth under Trumponomics would be higher for four reasons:
Despite the 1990s IT revolution, the US economy moved to a lower growth path during the 2000-10s that could well reflect the factors listed above (Chart 9). In addition, IT was a labour augmenting technical innovation and thus contributed to workers loss of bargaining power and lower income share. With Trumponomics and a credible central bank, the US economy could move to a higher growth path with stable if somewhat higher inflation.
Trumponomics success would likely bring about higher inflation and long-term unemployment, as well as a steeper Philipps curve. Higher inflation would reflect greater worker bargaining power and more of a conflict over income distribution. This ‘conflict theory of inflation’ has existed since the 1970s and is expressed by prominent economists such as James Tobin. It aligns well with the disinflation and loss of union power of the past 40 years (Charts 7 and 9).
By ‘higher inflation’, I mean inflation possibly higher but still near the Fed 2% target, and stable, which could be achieved through central bank credibility. This compares with inflation undershooting the Fed target in the three decades before the pandemic.
Also, a post Trumponomics economy could carry a higher long-term unemployment rate. This is because greater business formation and innovation could entail higher labour market churn. In addition, with lower profitability per workers, firms’ incentive to search for additional workers is lower. This is shown in whether the decrease in the long-term unemployment rate (NAIRU) was accompanied by an increase in profits per workers and a decrease in the ratio of actual hires relative to job openings (Chart 10)
But higher inflation and unemployment would not imply lower wellbeing. Rather they would reflect a more dynamic economy.
Lastly, stronger worker bargaining power could see a steeper Phillips curve, as stressed in a recent Fed paper. The intuition is that with weak market power, workers are unable to obtain much higher wages when the economy is hit with a positive demand shock. Instead, because hiring extra workers is so profitable, employers react by expanding employment. As a result, smaller changes in inflation are associated with larger changes in employment. These dynamics would work in reverse with stronger worker bargaining power.
Successful Trumponomics would have deep market implications
A market regime change would accompany a macro regime change. Real yields could rise further (Chart 11). Yields tend to track GDP growth with the spread between yields and GDP growth as a form of ‘macro risk premium’. In the low volatility environment of the 2000s and 2010s, yields have been below GDP. With higher inflation and a generally more volatile macro backdrop, real yields could climb above real GDP growth, aligning with the experience of the 1980s and 1990s (yields below GDP growth in the 1960s and 1970s reflected financial repression).
The combination of a declining profit share of income and higher real yields could see the ratio of equity market capitalization to GDP stabilize and even fall (Chart 12). As Bessent predicted, Wall Street would do well enough but perhaps not as well as in the past. This could end US equity outperformance (Chart 13).
With the end of US equity outperformance, US investors could seek greater international diversification of their portfolios and foreign investors could reduce their holdings of US equities. As a result, the equity balance could turn negative, supporting a weaker dollar (Charts 14 and 15).
Also, the negative bond-stock correlation could weaken or even turn positive (Chart 16). This is because bond and stocks negatively correlate with inflation, while stocks are correlated positively with growth but bonds negatively. In addition, the economy would be moving from a regime dominated by growth shocks to a regime dominated by inflation shocks.
Meanwhile, there could be factors and sector rotations. For instance, the growth stocks outperformance could end, and the outperformance of smaller banks relative to large ones, that tend to be more capital markets focused, could increase further.
Trumponomics has substantial upside, political and economic, but entails substantial implementation risks.
For instance, supporting stronger wage gains risks igniting a wage-price feedback loop. Managing these risks requires strong competition policy and a strong, independent central bank. Lower energy prices would mitigate these risks by engineering real wage growth with constant nominal wages.
Deportations of illegal migrants could shrink the workforce, depress consumption and trigger stagflation if migrants do not work out of fear of deportation.
Maintaining a ‘good enough’ equity market performance while shrinking profit income share would require a strong growth rate. Lower energy prices would also help maintain profits and equity performance outside of the energy sector.
Tariffs increases would need to be implemented in a predictable and gradual manner. This would minimize the unavoidable short-term costs associated with higher import prices (necessary to shift business investment) while increasing the risk of long-term gains.
Finally, there could be conflicts with the administration’s other goals. For instance, fiscal consolidation that in the short term could depress demand.
Following the administration’s multiple and inconsistent policy announcements, consumer and business confidence have fallen, and markets are now pricing 2.5 cuts by December, with a full cut at the June FOMC meeting.
I do not share this pessimism as the foundations of the expansion are solid and I expect the administration to correct course and strive for clearer messaging and pro-growth policies.
Even if I am wrong on the administration’s policies, I see them as having more of a detrimental impact on supply than on demand. This suggests the risks to inflation remain skewed to the upside. Therefore, I still expect no 2025 cuts, though my conviction is lower than a month ago.
Spring sale - Prime Membership only £3 for 3 months! Get trade ideas and macro insights now
Your subscription has been successfully canceled.
Discount Applied - Your subscription has now updated with Coupon and from next payment Discount will be applied.